Mortgage structure, saving rates and the wealth distribution

Luís Teles Morais

Nova School of Business and Economics


Nova Job Market Workshop
Nova SBE, Carcavelos, 5 September 2025

Introduction

How do fixed amortization schedules in mortgages affect
homeowners’ saving and the distribution of wealth?

Mortgage debt contracts are a large saving plan

  • Homeowners: \(\sim 60\%\) of saving is mortgage repayment in the Euro area (similar in US)
    • \(\sim 30\%\) of aggregate household saving
  • Repayment schedules are rigid, fixed at origination in very long-term contracts

  • In many countries (Euro area, US), only available structure is a fully amortizing annuity loan:

    • Fixed payment = interest + principal. Balance \(\rightarrow 0\) at maturity

Mandatory amortization schedule \(\Rightarrow\) \(\uparrow\) saving, \(\downarrow\) consumption
Bernstein and Koudijs (2024 QJE), Backman and Khorunzhina (2024), Backman et al. (2024); Larsen et al. (2024)

This paper. A theory of consumption/saving under different mortgage structures suggests:

  • This can be rationalized by a standard model of consumption and saving with simple friction
  • It may have large, heterogeneous effects on saving over the life cycle \(\rightarrow\) wealth distribution

This paper

Life cycle model of homeowners facing uninsurable income risk and a fixed amortization schedule

  • Precautionary saving mechanism can explain large effects in empirical literature
  • Effects are heterogeneous: younger, poorer homeowners save more; others unaffected
  • Matches novel stylized facts from household wealth data in the Euro area
    • Younger and lower-income/wealth homeowners with an amortizing mortgage save more
      • Homeowners 30-40y.o. in Europe save 2x more than renters/free users
      • No diff. among older, richer groups
      • Homeowners with interest-only mortgages similar to renters

Large implications of mandatory amortization for wealth accumulation & distribution

  • Saving rates of young and lower-income homeowners \(\uparrow\), but more financial fragility:
    • Total wealth-income ratios \(\uparrow\) for lower-income households
    • But liquid wealth to income \(\downarrow\)

Introduction

Contribution to the literature

  • Effects of mortgage amortization on household consumption and saving
    Backman and Khorunzhina (2024), Bernstein and Koudijs (2024), Backman et al. (2024); Larsen et al. (2024); Attanasio et al. (2021)
    • This paper: clarify role of precautionary saving mechanism + long-run effects
  • Optimal mortgage payment structure
    Boar et al. (2022); Balke et al. (2024), Boutros et al. (2025); Campbell and Cocco (2015), Campbell et al. (2018), Chambers et al. (2009), Greenwald et al. (2018), Guren et al. (2018), Piskorski and Tchistyi (2010, 2011)
    • This paper: (heterogeneous) effects on household wealth and welfare of repayment rigidity
  • Wealth distribution: housing drives dynamics through return rates
    Saez & Zucman 2016; Jorda et al. 2019 QJE, Fagereng et al 2020, Kuhn, Schularick & Steins 2020; Martinez-Toledano 2022
    • This paper: role of saving rates channel due to mortgage contract design

Agenda

  1. Introduction
  2. Model framework
  3. Data from Euro area countries
  4. Quantitative analysis
  5. Conclusion

Model

Model

Overview

Standard incomplete markets model + mortgage debt

  • First‐time homebuyer life‐cycle
    • Each agent lives 40 periods, from age 30 (“just bought a house”) to retirement at 70
  • Basic features:
    • Two asset types: liquid safe asset (risk‐free) vs. mortgage debt. Housing fixed
    • Idiosyncratic income risk (permanent + transitory)
  • Key addition – mortgage contract friction
    • Mandatory amortization schedule, transaction cost to reduce payments
    • How does this wedge affect saving and wealth accumulation?

Model

Household life cycle endowments and decisions

  • A home worth \(P_{0}\) (normalized) and a 30‐year fixed‐rate mortgage with initial balance \(M_{0}\)
  • Some initial financial wealth: \(A_{0}\) and exogenous risky earnings \(Y_{t}\) over the life cycle
  • Decide each period on how much to:
    • consume \(c_t\) and save each period
    • repay \(d_t\) of their mortgage debt

Households in the model maximise utility from non-housing consumption:

\[ U(c_{t}) = \frac{c_{t}^{\,1-\gamma}}{1 - \gamma} \]

  • Only non‐housing consumption enters utility (housing \(H\) fixed)
    • Assumption: prefs separable, so \(\text{argmax} \sum_t u(C_t) = \text{argmax} \sum_t u(C_t, \bar{H})\) (Campbell-Cocco 2015)

Model

Assets & mortgage frictions

Liquid saving and mortgage debt

  • Savings in the liquid asset (\(a_{t}\)) earn risk‐free interest
    • Borrowing limit \(\,a_{t} \ge 0\,\) (no unsecured debt)
    • Household cannot increase mortgage debt, only repay \(\,d_{t} \ge 0\,\)
  • Outstanding mortgage debt demands interest \(r + s\)

Mortgage repayment schedule

  • Mandatory amortization: \(D^{*}(m_{t-1},\,t)\) from standard annuity formula
    • Deviating from repayment schedule \(d_t < d_t^*\), then incurs transaction cost \(\tau_t > 0\)
  • If default, lose house and keep low consumption \(\underline{c}\) until end
    • Repayment usually feasible under calibration \(y: y > D^{*}(m_{t-1},\,t) + m_{t-1} (r+s)\)

Model

Period problem

\[ \max_{\,c_t,d_t}\; u(c_t)\;+\;\beta\, \mathbb E_t\bigl[V_{t+1}(y_{t+1},a_{t+1},m_{t+1})\bigr] \]

\[ \begin{aligned} a_{t+1} &= (1+r)\bigl[a_t + y_t - (r+s)m_t - d_t - \textcolor{red}{\tau_t}- c_t\bigr] \\[4pt] m_{t+1} &= m_t - d_t &\; \; m_t \ge 0,\; a_t \ge 0 \end{aligned} \]

  • Key friction: scheduled repayment \(d_t^{\!*}\), underpaying costs \(\textcolor{red}{\tau_t} \equiv \tau \cdot \max\{0, d_t^* - d_t\}\)

FOC for amortization trades-off marginal value of liquid asset accumulation vs. mortgage repayment

  • There’s a region of the state space \((a, y, m)\) where \(d_t < d_t^*\) preferable, absent the cost of delaying: \[ (1 + r - \tau) \mathbb{E}_t[V_a'] < \mathbb{E}_t[V_m'] < (1 + r) \mathbb{E}_t[V_a'] \]
  • If liquid assets/income low, but not too much \(\Rightarrow\) HH sticks with \(d_t^*\) and reduces \(c_t\), \(a_{t+1}\)
    • If \(\tau = 0\), HH would instead delay repayment (\(d_t < d_t^*\)), and increase \(c_t\), \(a_{t+1}\)
  • Far from liq. constraint \(\tau\) irrelevant

Model

Mechanism: how amortization frictions affect saving

Predictions for consumption and saving under mandatory amortization

  • Stronger effects for:
    • Younger: higher expected income growth, lower income, lower wealth (life cycle; down payment)
    • Lower-income: houses, mortgages indivisible
  • Little or no effect for wealthier or higher-income homeowners
  • Compared to:
    • Flexible repayment scheme (e.g. interest-only mortgages)
    • Renters and others
  • Consequence: higher saving rates for constrained mortgaged homeowners
    • Matches stylized facts in Euro area data \(\rightarrow\) life-cycle and income/wealth saving gradients

Data from euro area countries

Data from euro area countries

The Eurosystem HFCS - Household Finance and Consumption Survey

  • Harmonized survey of households in Euro area. Three waves (2013-14; 2016-17; 2020-21)
  • Compare:
    • Average across Euro area countries (except NL)
    • NL: mostly interest-only mortgages until 2013-14 policy change
  • Netherlands policy reform (2013):
    • Until 2013, interest-only mortgages dominated (≈ 60–70% of stock)
    • From 2013, full tax deductibility restricted to fully amortizing annuity loans – high cost of deferred payment
    • New borrowers forced to amortize → sharp rise in repayment flows

Amortizing mortgages increase saving at the beginning of life cycle

Saving rates over the life cycle (Age 65 = 100)

Amortizing mortgage increase saving only for poorer homeowners

Saving rates over the income distribution (Q5 = 100)

Share of income going to amortization declines with age and income

Amortization as % of net income

Over the life cycle:

Across income quintiles:

Quantitative analysis

Quantitative analysis

Income process: inelastic labor supply yields earnings \(Y_{t} = \Gamma_{t}Z_{t}\,\theta_{t}\), as standard: (Carroll & Samwick, 1997)

  • \(\Gamma_{t}\) = deterministic life‐cycle profile (grows until age 50, then flat)
  • \(\ln Z_{t} = \ln Z_{t-1} + \ln \psi_{t}\); \(\ln\psi_{t}\sim N\bigl(-\tfrac12\sigma_{\psi}^{2},\,\sigma_{\psi}^{2}\bigr)\) ; \(\ln \theta_{t}\sim N\bigl(-\tfrac12\sigma_{\theta}^{2},\,\sigma_{\theta}^{2}\bigr)\)

Initial conditions

  • A home worth \(P_{0}=5\) (5x annual permanent income)
  • A 30‐year fixed‐rate mortgage with \(M_{0} \le \theta^{M}P_{0}\) (LTV cap = 80 %)
  • A small initial liquid buffer: \(A_{0} = 1/12\) of annual income

Bequest motive at retirement (de Nardi, 2004):

\[ B\bigl(a_{T} - m_{T}) = \underline{b} ,\frac{\bigl(a_{T} - m_{T} + \overline{b}\bigr)^{\,1-\gamma}}{1 - \gamma}, \textrm{\; $\underline{b} , \overline{b}$ params} \]

  • Mortgage must be fully repaid by retirement \(\Leftrightarrow\) bequest is net wealth \(a_T - m_T\)

Quantitative analysis

Full dynamic household problem

In practice, solved in terms of consumption \(c_t\) and a transformed repayment share \(\psi_t\), where:

\[ \psi_t \equiv \frac{d_t}{y_t - (r + s)m_t - \tau_t - c_t} \quad \text{(share of saving used for mortgage repayment)} \]

The household solves the dynamic problem:

\[ V(t, s_t) = \max_{\{c_k, \psi_k\}_{k=t}^{T}} \; \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \sum_{k=t}^{T-1} \beta^{k-t} \frac{c_k^{1 - \gamma}}{1 - \gamma} + \beta^{T - t} B(a_T - m_T) \right], \; \textrm{s.t.} \]

\[ \begin{aligned} d_t &= \psi_t \cdot \left(y_t - (r + s)m_t - \tau_t - c_t \right) \\ a_{t+1} &= (1 + r)\bigl[a_t + y_t - (r + s)m_t - d_t - \tau_t - c_t\bigr] \\ m_{t+1} &= m_t - d_t \\ \tau_t &= \tau \cdot \max\{0, d_t^* - d_t\}, \quad a_t \ge 0, \quad m_t \ge 0, \quad d_t \ge 0 \end{aligned} \]

  • Solution: deep learning algorithm proposed by Duarte et al. (2022), Barrera & Silva (2024)

Quantitative analysis

Calibration

  • Model calibrated for NL (in progress)

  • Replicate regime change

    1. Pre-2013: Interest-only free (\(\tau = 0\))
    2. Post-2013: High cost of deferred payment (\(\tau = 0.25\))

Model HHs forced to amortize cut consumption until mortgage is repaid

Average age profiles of consumption and saving

Model HHs allowed to optimize backload repayment

Average age profiles of mortgage balance and wealth

Income-poorer model HHs save more in total, but less into liquid wealth

Means of model population across income quintiles (conditional on age)

Flattening of saving rate differences reproduces pattern in the data

  • Saving rates increase for lower income (and younger ages)

Forced amortization increases saving rates at the bottom of wealth dist.

Suggesting effects on distribution of total and financial wealth

  • Saving rates increase for groups at the bottom wealth groups
  • Sketch of implications for wealth distribution in realistic model

Conclusion

Conclusion

  • Mortgage debt repayment is an important part of household saving flows
  • Stylized facts from European survey data:
    • Young, low-income homeowners save significantly more than non-mortgaged peers
    • Netherlands interest-only mortgages reveal saving patterns closer to renters
  • Can be explained by precautionary saving response of homeowners facing:
  • Work in progress with model to:
    • Realistic estimation in the data: income, mortgage costs
    • Endogenize initial contract choice
    • Quantify implications for the wealth distribution

Thank you!

Reach out: luistelesm.github.io | luis.teles.m@novasbe.pt

Appendix

Appendix

Data: mortgage amortization in the HFCS

% of regular payment going to amortization

% of household income going to amortization

Back to main

Appendix

Amortization by wave

Back to main

Appendix

Amortization for mortgages before and after 2013

Percentage of obs. where amortization is less than 5% of the regular payment:

NL others
Mortgages before 2013 30.1 1.7
Mortgages on or after 2013 11.8 1.0

Back to main

Appendix

Interest rates

Back to main

Appendix

Amortization implied by annuity formula

  • If mortgage is an annuitized loan, the amortization paid as part of the installment in period \(t\) is: \[L\times r\times\left(\frac{1}{1-\frac{1}{(1+r)^{T-t}}}-1\right)\]
    • where \(L\) is the outstanding amount, \(r\) the loan rate and \(T\) the residual maturity.
  • This is what we observe for the median HH in the overall sample but not in NL:

Back to main

Appendix

Weight of regular mortgage payments on income

Back to main

Appendix

Saving rate measure checks

  • Match with self-reported ability to save:

  • HFCS aggregates vs. national accounts (QSA)

Back to main

Appendix

Data: saving rates in the HFCS

  • Saving rates increase with wealth for both

  • Decline in old age in NL
  • Interesting, as illiquidity of housing possible reason for plateau of saving (eg Yang 2009)

Back to main

Appendix

Data from Euro area countries

Saving rates over the wealth distribution (Q5 = 100)

Back to main

Appendix

Saving rates over the wealth distribution

Mortgaged homeowners vs. others

  • Waves 3 and 4:

Back to main

Appendix

Saving rates over the wealth distribution

Mortgaged homeowners vs. others

Back to main

Appendix

Saving rates over the life cycle

Saving by homeowners in NL and others

  • No substantial difference between post-policy reform mortgages

Back to main

Appendix

Saving rates over the wealth distribution

Saving by homeowners in NL and others

  • No substantial difference between post-policy reform mortgages

Back to main

Appendix

Age profiles of debt in the data

  • Life cycle profile of savings and mortgage debt
  • Strict subsample of households who:
    • Have never refinanced
    • Live in their first home
      • Roughly identified by age at purchase \(≤35\)
  • Interest-only mortgages: those for which amortization is \(<\) 80% implied by annuity formula

Appendix

Age profiles of debt in the data

Appendix

Age profiles of debt in the data

Appendix

Age profiles of debt in the data

Appendix

Model solution details

HH problem and solution

Basic principle uses stochastic gradient descent to find parameters of neural network that solve for the optimal policy function.

  • Machine learning techniques allow to compute the gradient \(\nabla_\theta \tilde{V}\left(s_0, \theta ; \hat{\pi}\right)\)
    • Computationally feasible with ML infrastructure, as neural networks are designed to work with problems with many dimension
    • JAX-based solution (implemented by Barrera & Silva, 2024, nndp)
    • Solved using Google Cloud TPU
  • Adjust \(\theta\) according to: \[ \Delta \theta = - \alpha \nabla_\theta \tilde{V}\left(s_0, \theta ; \hat{\pi}\right) \]
    • i.e., move in the direction that reduces the loss function (\(-V\)) the fastest
    • \(\alpha\) is the learning rate